Writing introduction for essay
Narrowing A Paper Topic Through Research
Friday, September 4, 2020
Checking in on New Years Resolutions... How Are Yours Going
Monitoring New Years Resolutions... How Are Yours Going In the event that you didnââ¬â¢t record your New Yearââ¬â¢s Resolutions in January, or regardless of whether you did, you may have totally disregarded them at this point. I realize that left to my own gadgets, I would be totally questionable with respect to returning on my guarantees from January. Fortunately, I have a blog and bulletin with a group of people to keep me responsible! As I glance back at my goals for my business in 2013, I understand I have prevailing with regards to satisfying 2 out of 6 of them. Wow! Letââ¬â¢s take a gander at the hard realities: 1. Distribute a Spanish-language rendition of How to Write a KILLER LinkedIn Profile. I connected with an advisor to investigate the chance of discovering somebody who needed remote rights to my digital book; nobody was intrigued. This implied if I somehow happened to distribute a Spanish adaptation of my book, I would need to do it without anyone's help. In the wake of considering the real factors of the expenses and exertion associated with amending the book in Spanish just as in English each time LinkedIn changes something in its foundation, I established that this task would not be a decent utilization of time and assets. I put a great deal of thought into this choice nonetheless! 2. Distribute a 50 Resume Tips book Iââ¬â¢m satisfied to declare that I will distribute not one but rather TWO digital books on resumes inside the following month: How to Write a WINNING Resume: 50 Tips to Reach Your Job Search Target and How to Write a STELLAR Executive Resume: 50 Tips to Reach Your Job Search Target. Watch my pamphlet for the official declaration about when the books will be accessible on Amazon! 3. Acquire a Master Resume Writer affirmation (CMRW) from Career Directors International. DONE as of March 2013! 4. Increment the school exposition/individual articulation bit of my business to 25% of all out business. I have not discovered the way to expanding the quantity of individual explanation customers I work with in a year. Confirmations season is going to begin, so I canââ¬â¢t make certain of the numbers for the year, however starting today affirmations counseling speaks to under 10% of The Essay Expertââ¬â¢s business (a year ago was somewhat more than 10%). In the event that you have thoughts of how to change that, if it's not too much trouble let me know-and please send customers on the off chance that you know anybody needing individual explanation instructing! 5. Start a preparation for continue authors. This undertaking never entirely got off the ground. I was centered around distributing the resume composing digital books and will return to the resume author preparing once the books increase some footing. My vision is to utilize the books as a schedule for preparing. On the off chance that you know any individual who might be keen on being prepared by me as a resume essayist, if you don't mind have them get in touch with me at BrendaB@TheEssayExpert.com. Much obliged to you! 6.à Create 213 examples of overcoming adversity! As of this composing my rundown isn't totally refreshed, yet I have around 50 examples of overcoming adversity to report. Iââ¬â¢m unquestionably behind on this objective. Some portion of the test is that numerous individuals don't keep me as refreshed as I might want about their pursuit of employment triumphs! In the event that youââ¬â¢re understanding this and you have gotten a meeting or employment in the wake of recruiting The Essay Expert or following my recommendation, if it's not too much trouble report to me at BrendaB@TheEssayExpert.com. Much obliged to you! Thatââ¬â¢s my report. How are you getting along on your New Yearââ¬â¢s goals? In the event that thereââ¬â¢s any way I can bolster you please let me know! Category:Life and LeadershipBy Brenda BernsteinSeptember 3, 2013
Tuesday, August 25, 2020
grahams gas law :: essays research papers
GAS LAWS Active ENERGY/GRAHAMââ¬â¢S LAW LAB Reason: To see how masses of iotas and atoms influence their pace of dispersion, and clarify our perceptions regarding mass, speed, motor vitality and temperature. Warm-up Question: 1. What is the meaning of temperature? Temperature is a proportion of the normal Kinetic Energy of the particles making a material. 2. What is the meaning of dissemination? Dissemination is an unconstrained spreading of particles until they are consistently circulated in their compartment. 3. If we increment the temperature of test of gas, at that point shouldn't something be said about the gas atoms should change? The gas atoms would start to speed up since the temperature would increment. 4. The component iodine (I2) diffuses more gradually than ethanol (CH3CH2CH2OH). Why would that be? Iodine is heavier in nuclear mass then ethanol, hindering its procedure to diffuse. Iodine weighs 253.6u while ethanol weighs 60.03u, giving ethanol a quicker disseminations rate. Strategy A: 1. Obtain a glass cylinder and wash it with water. Dry the outside of the cylinder with a paper towel. Next, spurt some CH3)2CO into the cylinder. A modest quantity is all that is required. At that point dry within the cylinder by going air through the cylinder (utilize a fan, the window, blow through it, and so forth.) 2. Use chalk to mark one finish of your lab station, "HC1," and the opposite end, "NH3." 3. Lay the glass tube on the table and spot the thermometer on the table close to the cylinder. 4. !!!CATION!!! THE NH3 AND THE HCI ARE IN VERY CONCENTRATED FORMS. Try not to ALLOW EITHER CHEMICAL TO COME INTO CONTACT WITH YOUR SKIN. On the off chance that THE NH3 OR HCl SPILLS, GET A DAMP PAPER TOWEL AND CLEAN IT UP IMMEDIATELY!!! 5. Obtain 1 little jug of HCI and 1 little container of NH3. Spot each jug in their individual parts of the bargains table. Get forceps, mark them, "HC1" or ââ¬Å"NH3"with tape, and spot them at their particular finish of the lab table. 6. Record the temperature of the air around the cylinder in the information table. 7. Separate the cotton ball into pieces sufficiently little to stuff into the parts of the bargains tube. Try not to place them into the cylinder yet. 8. While holding the cotton ball with the forceps, place 4 drops of HCl or NH3 (whichever compares to the name on the forceps). 9. Repeat stage 8 with the other concoction. You should now have two little cotton balls, one with 7 drops of HCI, one with 7 drops of NH3. Keep them at their separate parts of the bargains station.
Saturday, August 22, 2020
Myth. Why did myth survive the scientific and philosophic challenges Essay
Legend. For what reason did fantasy endure the logical and thoughtful difficulties of the old style Greek world - Essay Example For what reason did the legend endure the logical and philosophical difficulties of the traditional Greek world? Presentation: Myth is some thought or a conviction which is silly and invented and has started in the ancient occasions which appeared normally and unavoidably. The legends created because of the way that the unwelcoming condition that the crude man experienced. The starting point of the legend during the ancient occasions or during the adolescence of humanity may because of two reasons: one might be the dread that may have been made during an event of the common marvel, for example, thunder or tempest for instance, and another may be as a recognition of the occasions of the past. Thus, as the historical backdrop of the humanity created, the language and the practices additionally created alongside the fantasy. The religion, customs and the fantasies are totally evolved in equal yet are unmistakable from each other. The legends have an extraordinary part in the improvement of the religion. Be that as it may, comparing the fantasy with the religion is preposterous. Legend is the reaction of the humankind to the indigenous habitat (Graff, Fritz., et al., 1996). Throughout the hundreds of years, Greek culture created and experienced numerous adjustments in this setting of the fantasies. Until a couple of hundreds of years the Greeks were supporting legends and after the eighteenth century the Greeks used to allude the word fantasy by ââ¬Ëmuthosââ¬â¢ which implies stories and words and began protecting with the proof of the logical confirmations and realities alluded by ââ¬Ëlogosââ¬â¢. ... So interestingly, the legend is created out of absence of clarifications. Clarifications: Myth appeared to have solid musings on the territories where the logical and thinking doesn't deliver the outcomes. To clarify quickly, legend assumes a solid job where the thinking doesnââ¬â¢t appear to be a lot to offer. For instance, for the situation to hypothesize what occurs after the demise. A typical clarification is that passing is a reality and can happen to anyone paying little heed to their age and status of their living. In the event that we reason out this reality the following prompt inquiry emerges is that what might occur after death and it is identified with the great and the terrible lives the individual had survived out his/her lifetime. So as to clarify this inquiry it is sifted through that the spirit of the individuals who lived great lives would go to the Elysium and the spirit of the individuals who lived terrible lives would go to the Tartarus and rebuffed to the lev el of disagreeableness. Another part where the fantasy assumed its job is where there is questionable and nonexistent of chronicled confirmations. So these sorts of clarifications rely upon the social, social and the instructive foundation of the adherent and what is really accepted. Fortification: The support of the political, social and moral situation of the subject in the setting may likewise be a purpose behind the clarifications of the legends. For instance the Roman sovereign Nero used to distinguish him with Gods so as to control his picture. So as to dazzle this legend the head picture was thrown in the coins by the designers which would picture him as a divine being. Issues: The issues which made because of the support of the authority are social and social pressures, and issues. Accordingly a legend could be changed and controlled to
How to Find the Birthplace of Your Immigrant Ancestor
Instructions to Find the Birthplace of Your Immigrant Ancestor Once youve followed your family tree back to the foreigner predecessor, deciding his/her origination is the way in to the following branch in your family tree. Knowing only the nation isnt simply enough - youll as a rule need to get down to the town or town level to effectively find your predecessors records. While it appears to be a basic enough errand, a town name isnt in every case simple to discover. In numerous records, just the nation or perhaps area, state, or division of cause were recorded, however not the name of the actualâ ancestral town or ward. In any event, when a spot is recorded, it might just be the close by enormous city, since that was an increasingly unmistakable perspective for individuals curious about the district. The main hint Ive found to my third extraordinary granddads city/town of source in Germany, for instance, is his headstone that says he was conceived in Bremerhaven. However, did he truly originate from the large port city of Bremerhaven? Or then again is that the port he emigrated from? Is it safe to say that he was from a close by unassuming community, maybe somewhere else in the city-territory of Bremen, or the encompassing province of Niedersachsen (Lower Saxony)? To find a foreigners town or town of starting point you may need to assemble pieces of information from various sources. Stage One: Take Off His Name Tag! Pick up all that you can about your foreigner precursor with the goal that you will have the option to recognize him in pertinent records, and recognize him from others of a similar name. This incorporates: The migrants complete name including her center name or family name, if applicableA date of birth or the date of another occasion (marriage, migration, and so on.) with which you might have the option to distinguish your ancestorA spot of birth, regardless of whether it is only a nation of source for nowThe names of every single recognizable relative guardians, mate, kin, aunties, uncles, grandparents, cousins, and so forth. Outsiders frequently went with family members or went to go along with one who had recently emigrated. These names will likewise assist you with identifying your foreigners family in their nation of origin.Any other data that may help distinguish your precursor, including religion, occupation, companions, neighbors, and so forth. Dont neglect to ask relatives and even far off family members about your predecessors origin. No one can tell who may have individual information or significant records in their ownership. Stage Two: Search National Level Indexes Once youve decided the nation of root, search for a national list to imperative or common enrollment records (births, passings, relationships) or a national statistics or other identification for that nation in the timespan in which your precursor was conceived (for example common enrollment list for England Wales). In the event that such a record exists, this may give an alternate route to learning your predecessors spot of birth. You should, notwithstanding, have enough distinguishing data to perceive the outsider, and numerous nations don't keep up indispensable records at the national level. Regardless of whether you do find a specific applicant along these lines, you will in any case need to follow different strides also to check that your equivalent name individual in the old nation is really your precursor. Stage Three: Identify Records Which May Include the Place of Birth The following objective in your origination mission is to discover a record or other source that lets you know explicitly where to begin glancing in your predecessors nation of root. While looking, recollect that your predecessors last living arrangement before migration may not really be their place of birth. See investigate effectively done by others. Much of the time, different scientists have just discovered where the displaced person originated from. This incorporates looking through distributed lists and parentages, nearby life stories and town accounts, and databases of aggregated records.Locate unique records identified with the foreigners demise, for example, passing records, church records, tribute, burial ground records, and probate records. Eulogies distributed in ethnic papers are the destined to contain explicit data, for example, a town of origin.Check both common and church hotspots for a marriage record and records of the childrens births.Search different kinds of genealogical records which may uncover a predecessors town of starting point, including statistics records, court records, papers, and land and property records.Immigration records, for example, traveler records and naturalization records are another significant source in the quest for a settlers town of birth. W hile it might appear to be a superior spot to begin, you as a rule need the data found in past strides to empower you to find migration and naturalization records. In the United States, for instance, registration records may uncover whether a progenitor was naturalized. Quest for these records in each spot where the outsider lived, for the total timespan when the individual lived there and for quite a while after his demise. Make certain to examine accessible records in all wards that may have kept records about the person in question, including town, area, district, state, and national specialists. Be careful in your assessment of each record, making note of all recognizing subtleties, for example, the outsiders occupation or the names of neighbors, godparents, and witnesses. Stage Four: Cast a Wider Net Some of the time subsequent to inquiring about every conceivable record, you will even now be not able to discover a record of the old neighborhood of your settler progenitor. For this situation, proceed with the pursuit in the records of recognized relatives sibling, sister, father, mother, cousin, kids, and so on to check whether you can discover a spot name related with them. For instance, my incredible granddad emigrated to the United States from Poland yet was never naturalized and left no records of his particular town of cause. The town where they lived was recognized, notwithstanding, on the naturalization record of his oldest little girl (who was conceived in Poland). Tip!à Church baptismal records for offspring of foreigner guardians are another asset that can be important in a quest for settler sources. Numerous migrants settled in zones and went to temples with others of their equivalent ethnic and geographic foundation, with a cleric or pastor who likely knew the family. Once in a while this implies records prone to be more explicit than only Germany in recording a position of cause. Stage Five: Find it on a Map Distinguish and check the spot name on a guide, something that isn't generally as simple as it sounds. Regularly you will discover numerous spots with a similar name, or you may find that the town has changed wards or even vanished. It is significant here to connect with authentic maps and different wellsprings of data to be certain that you have recognized the right town.
Friday, August 21, 2020
Bibliography of Beethoven Berlioz and Chopin essays
Reference index of Beethoven Berlioz and Chopin papers Beethoven was conceived in Bonn, Germany in 1770 to Johann van Beethoven and his better half, Maria Magdalena. He took his first music exercises from his dad, who was tenor in the ensemble of the diocese supervisor balloter of Cologne. His dad was a temperamental, yet goal-oriented man whose unnecessary drinking, harsh temper and uneasiness shockingly didn't reduce Beethovens love for music. He considered and performed with incredible achievement, notwithstanding turning into the provider of his family unit when he was 18 years of age. His dads progressively genuine liquor issue and the prior death of his granddad in 1773 sent his family into extending destitution. From the outset, Beethoven had little effect on the melodic culture, regardless of his dads trusts. At the point when he turned 11, he left school and turned into an associate organist to Christian Gottlob Neefe at the court of Bonn, gaining from him and different performers. In 1783 he turned into the continuo player for the Bonn show and went with their practices on console. In 1787, he was sent to Vienna to take further exercises from Mozart. After two months, be that as it may, he was gotten back to Bonn by the demise of his mom. He began to play the viola in the Opera Orchestra in 1789, while likewise instructing in creating. He met Haydn in 1790, who consented to show him in Vienna, and Beethoven at that point moved to Vienna forever. He got budgetary help from Prince Karl Lichnowsky, to whom he committed his Piano Sonata in C minor, otherwise called The Pathtique . He performed openly in Vienna in 1795 just because, and distributed his Op. 1 and Op. 2 piano sonatas. His works are generally isolated into three periods. The first is known as the Viennese Classical, the second is the Heroic, and the third is Late Beethoven. In the primary time frame, his singularity and style progressively created, as he utilized numerous strategies from Haydn, including the utilization of quiet. He created for the most part for the piano ... <!
Sunday, August 2, 2020
Sample TOEFL Integrated Essay Endotherms
Sample TOEFL Integrated Essay Endotherms Sample TOEFL Integrated EssayThe QuestionThis integrated (Type 1) question is taken from theOfficial TOEFL iBT Tests CollectionfromETS. It also appeared on one of the TPO tests (number 4, I think).Special Offer: TOEFL Essay Evaluation and ScoringYou can now sign up to have your practice essays evaluated and scored by the author of this page. This service is a great way to learn how you will do before test day and how you can best prepare for the big day. Sign up today.The Sample Essay The reading and the listening are about whether or not dinosaurs were endotherms. The author of the reading feels there is evidence to suggest that dinosaurs were animals of this type. The professor, on the other hand, is not convinced of this. He casts doubt on each of the theories presented in the reading. First of all, the author points out that dinosaur fossils have been found in cold polar regions. It is noted that only animals that can maintain warm body temperatures, like endotherms, coul d have been active in climates of this type. The lecturer casts doubt on this claim. She observes that todayâs polar regions were much warmer during the time of the dinosaurs; warm enough for non-endotherms to inhabit them. Moreover, she observes that such animals could have migrated or hibernated during months when the temperatures actually were very cold. Secondly, the author contends that the dinosaurs were endotherms based on the structure of their legs. The article points out that dinosaurs had legs underneath their bodies, just like all modern endotherms. On the other hand, the lecturer notes that the leg structure of dinosaurs served merely to support their weight. She contends that having legs under their bodies allowed the dinosaurs to evolve to very large sizes, which was advantageous in many ways. Finally, the author makes a connection between endothermic animals and bone structure. The bones of dinosaurs contained bodies called Haversian canals, which helped th em to grow large, which is a common characteristic of endotherms. The professor challenges the validity of this point. She notes that dinosaur bones also show evidence of growth rings. She says that these rings indicate that the dinosaurs grew in spurts, which is a characteristic of non-endotherms.NoteThis is a sample TOEFL integrated essay written by a native speaker. It follows our TOEFL writing templates for integrated essays. If you find it useful, please remember that we have many more sample essaysfor you to read!
Thursday, June 25, 2020
Specific And Macroeconomic Determinants Essay Example Pdf - Free Essay Example
During the last two decades the banking sector has experienced worldwide major transformations in its operating environment. Both external and domestic factors have affected its structure and performance. Despite the increased trend toward bank disintermediation observed in many countries, the role of banks remains central in financing economic activity in general and different segments of the market in particular. A sound and profitable banking sector is better able to withstand negative shocks and contribute to the stability of the financial system. Therefore, the determinants of bank performance have attracted the interest of academic research as well as of bank management, financial markets and bank supervisors. The majority of studies on bank profitability, such as Short (1979), Bourke (1989), Molyneux and Thornton (1992), Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (2000) and Goddard et al. (2004), use linear models to estimate the impact of various factors that may be important in explaining profits. Even though these studies show that it is possible to conduct a meaningful analysis of bank profitability,à [1]à some issues are not dealt with sufficiently. First, the literature principally considers determinants of profitability at the bank and/or industry level, with the selection of variables sometimes lacking internal consistency, while there is no thorough investigation of the effect of the mac roeconomic environment, owing partly to the small time dimension of the panels used in the estimation. Second, in most of the literature, the econometric methodology is not adequately described and/or does not account for some features of bank profits (e.g. persistence), which implies that the estimates obtained may be biased and inconsistent. This paper investigates, in a single equation framework, the effect of bank-specific, industry-specific and macroeconomic determinants on bank profitability. The group of the bank-specific determinants of profitability involves operating efficiency and financial risk. Size is also included to account for the effect of economies of scale. The second group of determinants describes industry-structure factors that affect bank profits, which are not the direct result of managerial decisions. These are industry concentration and the ownership status of banks. The Structure-Conduct-Performance hypothesis figures prominently among theories that re late market power to bank profitability. The third group of determinants relates profitability to the macroeconomic environment within which the banking system operates. In this context, we include cyclical output and expected inflation among the explanatory variables. The current study represents one of the few attempts to identify the relationship between business cycle and bank profitability, and in doing so we use, on the one hand, a panel whose time dimension covers all the phases of the business cycle and, on the other, alternative techniques to measure the cycle. We utilize data from the Greek banking sector over a relatively long period (1985-2001). In specifying the model we account for profit persistence using a dynamic panel data estimation procedure. The empirical results suggest that bank-specific determinants, excluding size, significantly affect bank profitability in line with prior expectations. The evidence also indicates that profitability is procyclical, the ef fect of the business cycle being asymmetric. It is noteworthy that the industry variables are not important in explaining bank profitability, even though the Greek banking system evolved dynamically during the sample period (sizeable changes in industry concentration, entry of new banks, privatizations and MAs) and the market share of publicly-owned banks remained high (though it followed a declining trend). The paper is organized in the following manner. Section 2 discusses the existing literature on bank profitability. Section 3 describes the industry structure and the model specification. Section 4 presents the estimation method and the empirical results. Section 5 concludes the paper. 2. Literature review In the literature, bank profitability is usually expressed as a function of internal and external determinants. The internal determinants originate from bank accounts (balance sheets and/or profit and loss accounts) and therefore could be termed micro or bank-specific determinants of profitability. The external determinants are variables that are not related to bank management but reflect the economic and legal environment that affects the operation and performance of financial institutions. A number of explanatory variables have been proposed for both categories, according to the nature and purpose of each study. The research undertaken has focused on profitability analysis of either cross-country or individual countries banking systems. The first group of studies includes Haslem (1968), Short (1979), Bourke (1989), Molyneux and Thornton (1992) and Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (2000). A more recent study in this group is Bikker and Hu (2002), though it is different in scope; its emphasis is on the bank profitability-business cycle relationship. Studies in the second group mainly concern the banking system in the US (e.g. Berger et al., 1987 and Neely and Wheelock, 1997) or the emerging market economies (e.g. Barajas et al., 1999). All of the above studies examine combinations of internal and external determinants of bank profitability.à [2]à The empirical results vary significantly, since both datasets and environments differ. There exist, however, some common elements that allow a further categorization of the determinants. Studies dealing with internal determinants employ variables such as size, capital, risk management and expenses management. Size is introduced to account for existing economies or diseconomies of scale in the market. Akhavein et al. (1997) and Smirlock (1985) find a positive and significant relationship between size and bank profitability. Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998) suggest that the extent to which various financial, leg al and other factors (e.g. corruption) affect bank profitability is closely linked to firm size. In addition, as Short (1979) argues, size is closely related to the capital adequacy of a bank since relatively large banks tend to raise less expensive capital and, hence, appear more profitable. Using similar arguments, Haslem (1968), Short (1979), Bourke (1989), Molyneux and Thornton (1992) Bikker and Hu (2002) and Goddard et al. (2004), all link bank size to capital ratios,à [3]à which they claim to be positively related to size, meaning that as size increases especially in the case of small to medium-sized banks profitability rises. However, many other researchers suggest that little cost saving can be achieved by increasing the size of a banking firm (Berger et al., 1987), which suggests that eventually very large banks could face scale inefficiencies. The need for risk management in the banking sector is inherent in the nature of the banking business. Poor asset quality a nd low levels of liquidity are the two major causes of bank failures. During periods of increased uncertainty, financial institutions may decide to diversify their portfolios and/or raise their liquid holdings in order to reduce their risk. In this respect, risk can be divided into credit and liquidity risk. Molyneux and Thornton (1992), among others, find a negative and significant relationship between the level of liquidity and profitability. In contrast, Bourke (1989) reports an opposite result, while the effect of credit risk on profitability appears clearly negative (Miller and Noulas, 1997). This result may be explained by taking into account the fact that the more financial institutions are exposed to high-risk loans, the higher is the accumulation of unpaid loans, implying that these loan losses have produced lower returns to many commercial banks. Bank expenses are also a very important determinant of profitability, closely related to the notion of efficient management. There has been an extensive literature based on the idea that an expenses-related variable should be included in the cost part of a standard microeconomic profit function. For example, Bourke (1989) and Molyneux and Thornton (1992) find a positive relationship between better-quality management and profitability. Turning to the external determinants of bank profitability, it should be noted that we can further distinguish between control variables that describe the macroeconomic environment, such as inflation, interest rates and cyclical output, and variables that represent market characteristics. The latter refer to market concentration, industry size and ownership status.à [4] A whole new trend about structural effects on bank profitability started with the application of the Market-Power (MP) and the Efficient-Structure (ES) hypotheses. The MP hypothesis, which is sometimes also referred to as the Structure-Conduct-Performance (SCP) hypothesis, asserts that increased marke t power yields monopoly profits. A special case of the MP hypothesis is the Relative-Market-Power (RMP) hypothesis, which suggests that only firms with large market shares and well-differentiated products are able to exercise market power and earn non-competitive profits (see Berger, 1995a). Likewise, the X-efficiency version of the ES (ESX) hypothesis suggests that increased managerial and scale efficiency leads to higher concentration and, hence, higher profits. Studies, such as those by Smirlock (1985), Berger and Hannan (1989) and Berger (1995a), investigated the profit-structure relationship in banking, providing tests of the aforementioned two hypotheses. To some extent the RMP hypothesis is verified, since there is evidence that superior management and increased market share (especially in the case of small-to medium-sized banks) raise profits. In contrast, weak evidence is found for the ESX hypothesis. According to Berger (1995a), managerial efficiency not only raises pro fits, but may lead to market share gains and, hence, increased concentration, so that the finding of a positive relationship between concentration and profits may be a spurious result due to correlations with other variables. Thus, controlling for the other factors, the role of concentration should be negligible. Other researchers argue instead that increased concentration is not the result of managerial efficiency, but rather reflects increasing deviations from competitive market structures, which lead to monopolistic profits. Consequently, concentration should be positively (and significantly) related to bank profitability. Bourke (1989), and Molyneux and Thornton (1992), among others, support this view. A rather interesting issue is whether the ownership status of a bank is related to its profitability. However, little evidence is found to support the theory that privately-owned institutions will return relatively higher economic profits. Short (1979) is one of the few studies offering cross-country evidence of a strong negative relationship between government ownership and bank profitability. In their recent work, Barth et al. (2004) claim that government ownership of banks is indeed negatively correlated with bank efficiency. In contrast, Bourke (1989) and Molyneux and Thornton (1992) report that ownership status is irrelevant for explaining profitability. The last group of profitability determinants deals with macroeconomic control variables. The variables normally used are the inflation rate, the long-term interest rate and/or the growth rate of money supply. Revell (1979) introduces the issue of the relationship between bank profitability and inflation. He notes that the effect of inflation on bank profitability depends on whether banks wages and other operating expenses increase at a faster rate than inflation. The question is how mature an economy is so that future inflation can be accurately forecasted and thus banks can accordingly manage the ir operating costs. In this vein, Perry (1992) states that the extent to which inflation affects bank profitability depends on whether inflation expectations are fully anticipated. An inflation rate fully anticipated by the banks management implies that banks can appropriately adjust interest rates in order to increase their revenues faster than their costs and thus acquire higher economic profits. Most studies (including those by Bourke (1989) and Molyneux and Thornton (1992)) have shown a positive relationship between either inflation or long-term interest rate and profitability. Recently, Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (2000) and Bikker and Hu (2002) attempted to identify possible cyclical movements in bank profitability the extent to which bank profits are correlated with the business cycle. Their findings suggest that such correlation exists, although the variables used were not direct measures of the business cycle. Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (2000) used the annual growth rate of GDP and GNP per capita to identify such a relationship, while Bikker and Hu (2002) used a number of macroeconomic variables (such as GDP, unemployment rate and interest rate differential). The literature describing the profitability determinants of the Greek banking sector is sparse.à [5]à In an important contribution, Eichengreen and Gibson (2001) analyze bank- and market-specific profitability determinants for the 1993-1998 period, using a panel not restricted to commercial banks. Their study represents one of the few attempts to account for profit persistence in banking, the empirical results suggesting that the Greek banking sector is imperfectly competitive. Market-specific variables such as concentration ratios and market shares were found to have a positive but insignificant effect on alternative measures of profitability. The effect of size is non-linear, with profitability initially increasing with size and then declining. Eichengreen and Gibson (2001) state that the effect of staff expenses is positive and significant, possibly due to the fact that quality is important. Other issues addressed are the impact of leverage and liquidity (positive and significant for both determinants), of ownership (insignificant) and finally of two measures of labor productivity (value of loans and deposits per 100 workers) showing opposite effects on profitability. Overall, the existing literature provides a rather comprehensive account of the effect of internal and industry-specific determinants on bank profitability, but the effect of the macroeconomic environment is not adequately dealt with. The time dimension of the panels used in empirical studies is usually too small to capture the effect of control variables related to the macroeconomic environment (in particular the business cycle variable). Finally, sometimes there is an overlap between variables in the sense that some of them essentially proxy the same profitability determinant. It follows that studies concerning the profitability analysis of the banking sector should address the above issues more satisfactorily, in order to allow a better insight into the factors affecting profitability. 3. Model specification and data 3.1 Background The Greek banking sector provides an interesting context for studying bank profitability. The sector underwent significant changes during the last two decades. Since the mid 1980s it was extensively liberalized through the abolition of administrative interventions and regulations, which seriously hampered its development. The reforms were adopted gradually and supported the further improvement of the institutional framework and the more efficient functioning of banks and financial markets in general. This has created a new, more competitive economic environment, within which the banking sector nowadays operates. The objective of Greeces participation in EMU initiated efforts towards the further deregulation of the banking system and macroeconomic convergence. During the past few years, Greek banks tried to strengthen their position in the domestic market and acquire a size, partly through MAs, that would allow them to exploit economies of scale and have easier access to international financial markets. These changes, along with the adoption of new technology and the improvement of infrastructure, have been catalytic to the performance of bank profitability. In this paper, we investigate the profitability of Greek commercial banks over the period 1985 to 2001. The data sources are presented in the Appendix. 3.2 The model The general model to be estimated is of the following linear form:à [6] (1) where Ãâà Ãâà it is the profitability of bank i at time t, with i = 1,ÃÆ'à ¢Ã ¢Ã¢â¬Å¡Ã ¬Ãâà ¦,N; t = 1,ÃÆ'à ¢Ã ¢Ã¢â¬Å¡Ã ¬Ãâà ¦, T, c is a constant term, ÃÆ'Ã
½its are k explanatory variables and ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà µit is the disturbance with vi the unobserved bank-specific effect and uit the idiosyncratic error. This is a one-way error component regression model, where vi Ãâà Ãâà ¾ IIN (0, Ãâà Ãâà ³2v) and independent of uit Ãâà Ãâà ¾ IIN (0, Ãâà Ãâà ³2u). The explanato ry variables ÃÆ'Ã
½it are grouped, according to the discussion above, into bank-specific, industry-specific and macroeconomic variables. The general specification of model (1) with the Xits separated into these three groups is: (2) where the Xits with superscripts j, l and m denote bank-specific, industry-specific and macroeconomic determinants respectively. Furthermore, bank profits show a tendency to persist over time, reflecting impediments to market competition, informational opacity and/or sensitivity to regional/macroeconomic shocks to the extent that these are serially correlated (Berger et al., 2000). Therefore, we adopt a dynamic specification of the model by including a lagged dependent variable among the regressors.à [7]à Eq. (2) augmented with lagged profitability is: (3) where Ãâà Ãâà i,t-1 is the one-period lagged profitability and Ãâà Ãâà ¤ is the speed of adjustment to equilibrium. A value of Ãâà Ãâà ¤ between 0 and 1 implies that profits persist, but they will eventually return to their normal (average) level. A value close to 0 means that the industry is fairly competitive (high speed of adjustment), while a value of Ãâà Ãâà ¤ close to 1 implies less competitive structure (very slow adjustment).à [8] 3.3 Determinants of bank profitability Table 1 lists the variables used in this study. The profitability variable is represented by two alternative measures: the ratio of profits to assets, i.e. the return on assets (ROA) and the profits to equity ratio, i.e. the return on equity (ROE). In principle, ROA reflects the ability of a banks management to generate profits from the banks assets, although it may be biased due to off-balance-sheet activities. ROE indicates the return to shareholders on their equity and equals ROA times the total assets-to-equity ratio. The latter is often referred to as the banks equity multiplier, which measures financial leverage. Banks with lower leverag e (higher equity) will generally report higher ROA, but lower ROE. Since an analysis of ROE disregards the greater risks associated with high leverage and financial leverage is often determined by regulation, ROA emerges as the key ratio for the evaluation of bank profitability (IMF, 2002). Both ROA and ROE are measured as running year averages.à [9]à Fig. 1 presents ROA and ROE for the Greek banking sector. The two ratios follow similar paths, increasing over time with a spike in 1999.à [10] 3.3.1 Bank-specific profitability determinants Capital: We use the ratio of equity to assets (EA) to proxy the capital variable, when adopting ROA as the profitability measure.à [11]à Also, following Berger (1995b), we relax the assumptions underlying the model of one-period perfect capital markets with symmetric information.à [12]à Firstly, the relaxation of the perfect capital markets assumption allows an increase in capital to raise expected earnings. This positive impact can be due to the fact that capital refers to the amount of own funds available to support a banks business and, therefore, bank capital acts as a safety net in the case of adverse developments. The expected positive relationship between capital and earnings could be further strengthened due to the MAs that occurred and the significant fund-raising by banks from the Athens Stock Exchange in the period 1998-2000. Secondly, the relaxation of the one-period assumption produces an opposite causation, since it allows an increase in earnings to increase the capital ratio. Finally, the relaxation of the symmetric information assumption allows banks that expect to have better performance to credibly transmit this information through higher capital. In the light of the above, capital should be modeled as an endogenous (as opposed to a strictly exogenous) variable. Credit Risk: To proxy this variable we use the loan-loss provisions to loans ratio (PL).à [13]à Theory suggests that incr eased exposure to credit risk is normally associated with decreased firm profitability and, hence, we expect a negative relationship between ROA (ROE) and PL. Banks would, therefore, improve profitability by improving screening and monitoring of credit risk and such policies involve the forecasting of future levels of risk. Additionally, central banks set some specific standards for the level of loan-loss provisions to be adopted by the countrys banking system. In view of these standards, bank management adjusts provisions held for loan losses, the level of which is decided at the beginning of each period. Thus, credit risk should be modeled as a predetermined variable. Productivity: In recent years banks have faced severe competition due to the lowering of barriers to entry and the globalization of the industry, which has forced them to reorganize. They have been targeting high levels of productivity growth both by keeping the labor force steady and by increasing overall output. During the period 1985-2001 labor productivity of Greek banks grew at an average annual rate of 2.5%. To examine whether the observed improvements in productivity growth have benefited bank profits, we include the rate of change in labor productivity (measured by real gross total revenue over the number of employees) in the model. Expenses management: The total cost of a bank (net of interest payments) can be separated into operating cost and other expenses (including taxes, depreciation etc.). From the above, only operating expenses can be viewed as the outcome of bank management. The ratio of these expenses to total assets is expected to be negatively related to profitability, since improved management of these expenses will increase efficiency and therefore raise profits. This expected negative correlation applies in particular to the Greek case, where personnel expenses are affected by relatively low productivity and the excess capacity of the larger publicly-owned banks. Size: One of the most important questions underlying bank policy is which size optimizes bank profitability. Generally, the effect of a growing size on profitability has been proved to be positive to a certain extent. However, for banks that become extremely large, the effect of size could be negative due to bureaucratic and other reasons. Hence, the size-profitability relationship may be expected to be non-linear. We use the banks real assets (logarithm) and their square in order to capture this possible non-linear relationship.à [14] 3.3.2 Industry-specific profitability determinants Ownership: A relationship between bank profitability and ownership may exist due to spillover effects from the superior performance of privately-owned banks compared with publicly-owned banks, which do not always aim at profit maximization. Although, as indicated in the literature review, there is no clear empirical evidence to support such a view, the peculiarity of the Greek banking sector where the share of commercial banks under public ownership was relatively high until the early 1990s makes the examination of the hypothesis appealing. To test this hypothesis, we follow the literatures suggestion in using a dummy variable. Alternatively, we use the market share (in terms of assets) of privately-owned banks in the sector. Concentration: To examine the SCP hypothesis, we use the Herfindahl-Hirschman (H-H) index.à [15]à In the first decade of the sample period, the Greek banking industry could be characterized as oligopolistic (Eichengreen and Gibson, 2001). About half of the sectors share belonged to the leading firm. Steadily, competitive practices increased through the strengthening of the private sector and the establishment of new commercial banks, until 1996 when a series of MAs started, causing the reversion of the decreasing trend of the H-H index (Fig. 2). In the recent literature on the SCP hypothesis, alternative indicators of the degree of compet ition in banking are provided by the estimation of the Lernerà [16]à and the Rosse-Panzarà [17]à indices, which are usually referred to as non-structural measures of competition. The argument is that the structural measures (i.e. the H-H index and concentration ratios) were found to have a weak relationship with profitability, when market shares were also included in the regressions. The results generally show that the non-structural measures of competition are not correlated with concentration, i.e. competition could be present in markets even with a relatively high degree of concentration. However, the use of non-structural measures in the profitability function has some major limitations. For example, the Rosse-Panzar test can give misleading results if the banks in the sample have not completely adjusted to market conditions,à [18]à and this leads to a bias toward the spurious appearance of market power. Similarly, in order to use the Lerner index, one has to effecti vely proxy bank output and then estimate the marginal cost using an appropriate functional form. The estimation of a cost function requires several assumptions concerning the methodology to be used, which is beyond the scope of the present work.à [19]à Hence, without denying its limitations, we proceed with using the H-H index. 3.3.3 Macroeconomic profitability determinants Inflation expectations: As discussed in the literature review, the relationship between expected inflation (or long-term interest rate, which incorporates inflation expectations) and profitability is ambiguous. We proxy expected inflation by current inflation, while the long-term interest rate is measured by the 10-yr government bond yield. In the Greek economy, CPI inflation and the 10-yr bond yield were relatively high until 1990, but thereafter disinflation started, which lasted until the end of the sample period. Cyclical output: In the present study, we explore the relationship between bank prof itability and the business cycle. There are several reasons why bank profitability may be procyclical. Firstly, lending could decrease during cyclical downswings, since such periods are normally associated with increased risk. In a similar context, provisions held by banks will be higher due to the deterioration of the quality of loans, and capital could also have a procyclical behavior, as equity tends to follow the phase of the cycle. Hence, in the absence of a business cycle variable, its effect on profitability could be partly captured by the relevant bank-specific variables. Secondly, demand for credit and stock market transactionsà [20]à would be strengthened substantially during economic booms and the interest margin may widen. Therefore, revenues could grow faster than costs leading to increased profits, while the opposite may hold true during economic slowdowns. To date, the literature has not focused explicitly on the effect of the business cycle on bank profitabili ty, since much of it uses cross-sections or panels with a small time dimension. Furthermore, the measures used to proxy the cyclical behavior of economic activity are not always appropriate. The present study attempts to move a step further as two methods for estimating cyclical output are considered. One uses the deviations of real GDP from its segmented trend, while the other uses the deviations of GDP from the trend calculated by applying the Hodrick-Prescott (1980) filter.à [21]à The two measures of the output gap are shown in Fig. 3. In periods during which GDP exceeds its trend, the output gap is positive, and if profitability is procyclical we expect it to rise. Similarly, when GDP is below trend, we expect profits to fall. Finally, we explore the possibility that this correlation may be asymmetric depending on whether the economy is above or below trend. These effects will be investigated by splitting the business cycle variable into two separate variables; the first inc ludes the years that output gap is positive and the second the years that output gap is negative. 4. Empirical results 4.1 Econometric methodology The present study uses an unbalanced panelà [22]à of Greek commercial banks spanning the period 1985-2001 (summary statistics of the variables used are presented in Table 2). Model (3) forms the basis of our estimation. In static relationships the literature usually applies least squares methods on Fixed or Random Effects models. However, in dynamic relationships these methods produce biased (especially as the time dimension T gets smaller) and inconsistent estimates. The econometric analysis of model (3) confronts the following issues: First, we test for stationarity of the panel, using a unit root test for unbalanced panels. Second, we examine whether individual effects are fixed or random. Third, we use techniques for dynamic panel estimation that deal with the biasedness and inconsistency of our estimates. Fourth, for the reasons discussed in Section 3, we examine whether the capital variable is endogenous and the risk variable predetermine d. Finally, we check for the presence of unobservable time effects and the robustness of the estimates. In what follows, we discuss these issues in turn. The use of a relatively large T in a model of bank profitability may be criticized on grounds of non-stationarity of the panel. Maddala and Wu (1999) suggest the use of the Fisher test, which is based on combining the p-values of the test-statistic for a unit root in each bank. They state that not only does this test perform best compared to other tests for unit roots in panel data, but it also has the advantage that it does not require a balanced panel, as do most tests. The results of this test are presented in Table 3. The null of non-stationarity is rejected at the 5% level for all variables but size. We continue with the estimation of the model not excluding this variable, since we are less likely to get spurious results given that the dependent variable is stationary. This is especially true if exclusion of the size variab le does not affect the models performance. The second issue is the choice between a fixed effects (FE) and a random effects (RE) model. As indicated by the Hausman test on model (3) (see Table 4), the difference in coefficients between FE and RE is systematic, providing evidence in favor of a FE model. Furthermore, the estimation results show that individual effects are present, since the relevant F-statistic is significant at the 1% level.à [23]à However, as mentioned above, the least squares estimator of the FE model in the presence of a lagged dependent variable among the regressors is both biased and inconsistent.à [24]à Monte Carlo studies that measured the corresponding bias in the coefficients of the lagged dependent and the independent variables (see for example Judson and Owen, 1999 or Hsiao et al., 2002) have found that the bias is significant for small values of T, but goes to zero as T increases. For the panel size of the present study, under certain values of the parameters, the average bias has been estimated to be in the range of 6%.à [25]à The relatively small size of the panel (N=21) is not a serious potential problem according to Judson and Owen (1999).à [26] The first attempt to deal with the problem of bias and inconsistency in dynamic models was made by Anderson and Hsiao (1982), who suggested an instrumental variables estimator based on the first-differenced form of the original equation. Arellano and Bond (1991) note that the Anderson-Hsiao estimator lacks efficiency as it does not exploit all the available instruments. They suggest that efficiency gains can be obtained by using all available lagged values of the dependent variable plus lagged values of the exogenous regressors as instruments.à [27]à Yet, the Arellano and Bond estimator has been criticized when applied to panels with very small T, the argument being that under such conditions this estimator is inefficient if the instruments used are weak (see Arel lano and Bover, 1995 and Blundell and Bond, 1998). However, in the present study T=17, which is large enough to avoid such problems. Consequently, we will proceed with the estimation of our model using the GMM estimator in the Arellano and Bond paradigm.à [28] Two issues remain to be dealt with in order to design a suitable model. Firstly, we should confirm that capital is better modeled as an endogenous variable and credit risk as a predetermined variable. We test this by running the same model twice, the first time with the two variables treated as strictly exogenous and the second time as endogenous and predetermined respectively. The results support the hypothesis that capital is better modeled as an endogenous variable and credit risk as predetermined (as the theory also suggests) since the Sargan test for over-identifying restrictions indicates that this hypothesis is rejected in the first case, while it is strongly accepted in the second.à [29] Finally, it is possib le that, given the large time frame of our dataset and the developments that took place in the Greek banking sector during the sample period, time effects are present in the error component of the model, as follows: (4) where ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà »t is the unobservable time effect. The joint significance of the unobservable time effects is tested by the H0 hypothesis: H0: ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà »2 = ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà »3 ÃÆ'à ¢Ã ¢Ã¢â¬Å¡Ã ¬Ãâà ¦ = ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà »T = 0, (5) The relevant LM test (Table 5) shows that H0 is rejected at the 95% confidence level, implying that we should include year-specific dummy variables to account for ÃÆ'Ã
½Ãâà »t. We experimented with many dummies and, as it turns out, the only significant coefficient is that of the 1999 dummy (due to the exceptional developments that took place in the stock market that year). Therefore, we expand Eq. (4) as follows: (6) where D99 is the dummy variable for the year 1999. The LM test for model (6) d oes not reject H0 (see Table 5) and thus we proceed with the estimation of this model. 4.2 Results Table 6 reports the empirical results of the estimation of model (6) using ROA as the profitability variable.à [30]à We use two alternative measures of ownership (a dummy variable or the market share of privately-owned banks) and of inflation expectations (the actual inflation rate or the long term interest rate). We also test for asymmetry in the effect of the business cycle by distinguishing years with positive and negative output gaps. Finally, the relevant specification tests for each estimated equation are presented. The model seems to fit the panel data reasonably well, having fairly stable coefficients, while the Wald test indicates fine goodness of fit and the Sargan test shows no evidence of over-identifying restrictions. Even though the equations indicate that negative first-order autocorrelation is present, this does not imply that the estimates are inconsistent . Inconsistency would be implied if second-order autocorrelation was present (Arellano and Bond, 1991), but this case is rejected by the test for AR(2) errors (see Table 6). Comparing the FE and the GMM estimates in Tables 4 and 6 respectively, one notes that the results produced by the two methods are similar. In the first estimates, standard errors are biased, as discussed previously, although the bias is expected to be small. Indeed, the difference in the coefficients between the two estimation methods is found to be of the order of 5% to 10%. The highly significant coefficient of the lagged profitability variable confirms the dynamic character of the model specification. In the present study, takes a value of approximately 0.35, which means that profits seem to persist to a moderate extent, and implies that departures from a perfectly competitive market structure in the Greek banking sector may not be that large. This finding is close to the estimate reported in Gibson (2005) for Greek banks. In contrast, Goddard et al. (2004) find that the statistical evidence for profit persistence in European banks is weak. Turning to the other explanatory variables, the coefficient of the capital variable (EA) is positive and highly significant, reflecting the sound financial condition of Greek banks. A bank with a sound capital position is able to pursue business opportunities more effectively and has more time and flexibility to deal with problems arising from unexpected losses, thus achieving increased profitability. The endogeneity of capital implies that the assumption of the one-period perfect capital markets model is not accepted for the Greek banking system. The effect of capital on profitability in the present study is only half of the effect found by Bourke (1989) for a panel of European, North American and Australian banks and by Molyneux and Thornton (1992) for the European banking industry, but almost the same as that found by Demirguc-Kunt and Huizi nga (1998) who used a large panel of banks from 80 countries. As expected, credit risk is negatively and significantly related to bank profitability. This shows that in the Greek banking system managers, attempting to maximize profits, seem to have adopted a risk-averse strategy, mainly through policies that improve screening and monitoring credit risk.à [31] We find productivity growth has a positive and significant effect on profitability.à [32]à This suggests that higher productivity growth generates income that is partly channeled to bank profits. In other words, banks increase their profits from improved labor productivity, which, among other things, is a result of the higher quality of newly hired labor and the reduction in the total number of employees. Operating expenses appear to be an important determinant of profitability. However, their negative effect means that there is a lack of competence in expenses management since banks pass part of increased cost t o customers and the remaining part to profits, possibly due to the fact that competition does not allow them to overcharge. Clearly, efficient cost management is a prerequisite for improved profitability of Greek banks, which have not reached the maturity level required to link quality effects from increased spending to higher bank profits. All estimated equations show that the effect of bank size on profitability is not important.à [33]à An explanation for this may be that small-sized banks usually try to grow faster, even at the expense of their profitability. In addition, newly established banks are not particularly profitable (if at all profitable) in their first years of operation, as they place greater emphasis on increasing their market share, rather than on improving profitability. If we remove the size variable from the estimations, the rest of the coefficients are not affected, which implies that the non-stationarity of this variable does not affect the performance of the model. As with the effect of size, the ownership status of Greek banks appears to be insignificant in affecting their profitability, whether it is proxied by a dummy variable or by the market share of the privately-owned banks. This is a striking result since the market share of these banks increased from about 20% in 1985 to 45% in 2001, mainly due to MAs and privatizations. Despite this development, privately-owned banks do not appear relatively more profitable, possibly denoting that the effects of MAs on bank profitability have not yet arisen. The empirical results show that concentration affects bank profitability negatively, but this effect is relatively insignificant. Hence, this study finds no evidence to support the SCP hypothesis. This outcome is in accordance with Berger (1995a) and other more recent studies, which claim that concentration is usually negatively related to profitability once other effects are controlled for in the profitability equation.à [3 4]à In the present study, two shortcomings emerge: Firstly, as discussed above, the relatively low value of the coefficient of the lagged profitability variable is consistent with low market power. Secondly, and in line with Berger (1995a), our estimations show that even though there was a considerable fall in the H-H index up until 1997 (when a series of mergers started to occur),à [35]à suggesting that the industry was moving to a more competitive structure and hence profitability should have declined, the improvement of the managerial practices (captured by the bank-specific variables) resulted in increased profitability. An important finding of this study is that the business cycle significantly affects bank profits, even after controlling for the effect of other determinants, which have a strong correlation with the cycle (e.g. provisions for loan losses). We further test for asymmetry in the effect of the business cycle, distinguishing between periods in which output is above its trend value and those in which it is below (see Eq. 4 of Table 6). We find that the coefficient of cyclical output almost doubles when output exceeds its trend value. In contrast, when output is below its trend, the coefficient of cyclical output is insignificant. This result supports the view that banks are able to insulate their performance during periods of downswings. Finally expected inflation, as proxied by the previous periods actual inflation, positively and significantly affects profitability, possibly due to the ability of Greek banks management to satisfactorily, though not fully, forecast future inflation, which in turn implies that interest rates have been appropriately adjusted to achieve higher profits. This may also be viewed as the result of bank customers failure (in comparison to bank managers) to fully anticipate inflation, implying that above normal profits could be gained from asymmetric information. Since during the period examined the Greek ec onomy went through a disinflation process, the estimated positive relationship between bank profitability and inflation is associated with the fact that interest rates on bank deposits decreased at a faster rate than those on loans. Similar estimates were obtained by using the interest rate variable instead of the inflation variable (see Eq. 3). 5. Conclusions In this paper, we specified an empirical framework to investigate the effect of bank-specific, industry-specific and macroeconomic determinants on the profitability of Greek banks. Novel features of our study are the analysis of the effect of the business cycle on bank profitability and the use of an appropriate econometric methodology for the estimation of dynamic panel data models. We find that capital is important in explaining bank profitability and that increased exposure to credit risk lowers profits. Additionally, labor productivity growth has a positive and significant impact on profitability, while operating expenses are negatively and strongly linked to it, showing that cost decisions of bank management are instrumental in influencing bank performance. The estimated effect of size does not provide evidence of economies of scale in banking. Likewise, the ownership status of the banks is insignificant in explaining profitability, denoting that private banks do not in gen eral make relatively higher profits, at least during the period under consideration. Also, the SCP hypothesis is not verified, as the effect of industry concentration on bank profitability was found insignificant. Therefore, this result is in line with theoretical considerations according to which concentration is not related to profitability, once the other effects are controlled for in the model. Finally, macroeconomic control variables, such as inflation and cyclical output, clearly affect the performance of the banking sector. The effect of the business cycle is asymmetric since it is positively correlated to profitability only when output is above its trend. Overall, these empirical results provide evidence that the profitability of Greek banks is shaped by bank-specific factors (that are affected by bank-level management) and macroeconomic, control variables that are not the direct result of a banks managerial decisions. Yet, industry structure does not seem to significa ntly affect profitability. The approach followed in this paper may well have considerable potential as a tool for exploring bank profitability determinants with the purpose of suggesting optimal policies to bank management. Data appendix Net profits before taxes, total assets, total shareholders equity, loan loss provisions, the value of total loans, gross total revenue and operating expenses are all from end-year bank balance sheets and profit/loss accounts (unconsolidated statements). The total number of bank employees was obtained from Bank of Greece data. Market shares are calculated by dividing the assets of bank i by total assets of the sector, and the H-H index is calculated as , where MS is market share. Data on the CPI and real GDP were taken from the National Statistical Service of Greece and on the 10-yr government bond yield from Eurostat. Cyclical output is the logarithmic deviation of GDP from a segmented trend or a trend calculated on the basis of the HP filter.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)